Here’s Tyler Cowen:
Excess reserves held at the Fed are down from their peak of about $2.8 trillion, but still close to $2 trillion, massively higher than their long-run historical average.
Inflationary pressures are modestly higher than they had been, but still in the range of roughly two percent. . . .
Since the liquidity trap is gone, and inflation remains well under control, the liquidity trap does not seem to be the reason why inflation did not explode post-2008, following the Fed’s stabilization measures.
No one is admitting this simple reality, which is staring us in the face.
I’d point to two different policy regimes:
1. During the first 53 years of my life, the Fed controlled inflation by adjusting the quantity of base money, often with the intermediate objective of influencing the fed funds rate. During that period, short-term risk free rates were positive. Because base money paid no interest it was a very poor investment, except for currency hoarders trying to shield income from the authorities. When the Fed injected new base money it was a sort of hot potato. The economy got rid of excess cash balances by spending them, forcing prices higher. Banks held very few excess reserves.
2. Since 2008, the Fed has controlled inflation by adjusting both the supply and the demand for base money, but mostly the demand. Since 2008, the rate of interest on reserves has no longer been lower than risk-free market rates. Since 2008, base money is no longer much of a hot potato, and thus it’s possible to sharply increase the monetary base without creating much inflation.
Tyler’s right that we are no longer in a liquidity trap. And he’s right that this fact has often been ignored and that this ignorance is unfortunate. But he’s wrong about the specific problem. When you are in a liquidity trap, the reason big monetary injections are not highly inflationary is that the interest rate on base money is roughly equal to the interest rate on other risk-free assets. But that’s still true, even after 2015. So one would not expect the recent inflation outcome to be much different than what we saw under the 7-year long liquidity trap (December 2008 to December 2015.)
Here’s what Tyler should have said:
In December 2015, the US exited the liquidity trap. At that moment, all “old Keynesian” discussion of problems allegedly caused by the liquidity trap should have immediately ceased. These problems were no longer being caused by a liquidity trap. For instance, Keynesians had blamed the liquidity trap for the slow recovery, and the undershooting of the 2% inflation target. They argued that fiscal austerity was contractionary due to the liquidity trap. They argued that big trade surpluses in countries like China and Germany tended to reduce AD in the US, because of the liquidity trap. All of these are arguments that only apply in an actual liquidity trap, where the Fed cannot cut rates further. And even that ignores the possibility of negative IOR. Even if correct (I don’t think they were), these Keynesian arguments should have ended in December 2015, but they didn’t.
After December 2015, we were no longer at the zero bound. The Fed had control of interest rates and monetary offset was fully operative. The Fed was clearly in control of monetary policy. Yes, the decision to pay IOR made monetary policy somewhat ineffective, but that was the Fed’s choice, not a “trap”. That’s the reality that was starring us in the face after December 2015, and which many old Keynesians ignored.
READER COMMENTS
Alan Goldhammer
Aug 27 2018 at 7:52am
I am not an economist so I’m probably walking out on thin ice. That being said, domestic manufacturing costs until the advent of the latest tariffs have been remarkably stable. One major driver is workplace wages have been stagnant for some time even as full employment is reached. The price of oil has seen normal fluctuations as judged by my periodic trips to the gas station. Except for certain limited geographic areas housing costs have experienced major rises. Almost every consumer good that my wife and I purchase is at prices similar to those of pre-recession accounting for the slight inflation of the past 10 years. Obviously some of this (most?) is a result of internet shopping and the ability to quickly find the best price.
If the demand side of the equation is relatively stable how can there be inflation?
Scott Sumner
Aug 27 2018 at 11:35am
Alan, I’m not sure what you are asking. What equation?
Alan Goldhammer
Aug 27 2018 at 11:46am
Scott – I’m not asking about an equation, only noting that by and large consumer prices are extremely stable and income for maybe 90% of working Americans has not budged at all. What I am trying to say is, if income and demand are relatively constant, inflation will be minimal. In the past energy prices have been inflationary drivers but that is not the case today. Gas prices are stable and the cost to heat, cool, and provide electricity for our house has really not changed much in the past 10 years (this is when I started monthly data collection).
I’m just trying to look at this from a consumer point of view.
Max
Aug 27 2018 at 8:31am
Question: What about savers? It’s nice to know that the economy as a whole is back on track but at least here in Europe it meant a stark depreciation of savings, an amount of credit that will never be paid back (Greece see latest comment by Mr Scholz) and a death sentence for most insurance companies that have private pensions funds and even private health care insurances.
JFA
Aug 27 2018 at 10:33am
Scott, I have always been curious about the link between wages and inflation, and Alan mentions it above. Could you talk about how increasing wages cause inflation (or if there is that relationship)?
Jerry Brown
Aug 27 2018 at 11:22am
JFA, you might want to look at a recent short post by Scott- it might address your question.
https://www.econlib.org/the-problem-with-sticky-price-models/
Scott Sumner
Aug 27 2018 at 11:36am
JFA, I’s more useful to think in terms of monetary policy causing both wage and price inflation.
JFA
Aug 27 2018 at 1:21pm
I agree, but I think you might be one of the few people who actually think that. I see economist talking about how they’d be worried if wages rise to fast because that will cause inflation (I think I’ve heard Betsy Stevenson say almost exactly that). I’ve always been of the view that “inflation is always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon”. It’s been a while since grad macro, but it seems few economist these days think of inflation as a solely a monetary phenomenon.
Scott Sumner
Aug 27 2018 at 2:14pm
The question of whether inflation is solely a monetary phenomenon is partly semantic. Thus if you target NGDP growth at 4%, then a wage shock such as a 15 dollar minimum wage will reduce RGDP and cause a one-time increase in prices. Ditto for an oil embargo.
On the other hand, with a completely effective 2% inflation target neither of those shocks raises inflation.
Again, I think it’s most useful to view inflation as being monetary, but there are other perspectives than can be defended.
If wage inflation rises on its own (not due to regulations), you must ask why this is happening—it’s a good bet monetary policy is the answer.
P Burgos
Aug 27 2018 at 11:29am
@JFA
The traditional story about inflation was that the Central Bank expanded the money supply, but that such an expansion didn’t lead to much of an expansion in the real productive resources in the economy. So to make a return on investment above that on Treasuries, businesses had to go out and spend money on things, but since there wasn’t any more productive resources than before, they would have to offer employees (and businesses) more money for their services than was previously paid, which push up inflation in the absence of strong productivity gains.
If I am understanding Prof. Sumner correctly, I don’t think that there needs to be a strict relationship between nominal wages and inflation. If productivity gains are strong, injecting a lot of hot money in the system might even help speed up the growth of the economy, as the increasing wages help speed up reallocation of resources as they drive unproductive enterprises out of business.
JFA
Aug 27 2018 at 1:38pm
Thanks P Burgos. I get the usual story (which you summarized quite nicely), but I hear (more often these days) economists and economics journalists alike treating potential increasing wages as a primary (rather than intermediate) cause of inflation.
P Burgos
Aug 27 2018 at 3:53pm
Thanks for the clarification. My best guess is that the people treating potentially increasing wages must be assuming that productivity isn’t going to grow very quickly, such that increasing wages across the board would have to be inflationary. That is at least my best guess. I suspect that they are thinking back to the stagflation of the 1970s as well.
chuck martel
Aug 27 2018 at 7:21pm
If it’s a fact that higher wages cause inflation then why isn’t it also a fact that higher stock prices do so as well? In order for there to be a price for a share of stock it must be sold to a buyer. If the seller receives more than was paid for that share he now has more money, just as if the candlestick maker got a bigger paycheck. He’s not required to re-invest that money in more stocks. In fact, he’s likely to spend it on a vacation to Capri, a new bass boat, Bo-tox therapy for his wife or a condo in Aspen.
The amount of wages workers receive can’t and doesn’t change the value of money. The amount of money circulation does.
Bob Murphy
Aug 27 2018 at 7:31pm
Great post, Scott.
Scott Sumner
Aug 27 2018 at 10:06pm
Thanks Bob.
Comments are closed.