Alan Blinder writes:
Thursday’s surprising report on first-quarter gross domestic product may contribute to a feeling of déjà vu all over again. High inflation reminds many Americans of the unhappy 1970s, when a series of food-price shocks in 1973-74 and a huge oil-price shock late in 1973 drove inflation through the roof—and a serious recession followed. Are we headed for a repeat performance?
Not quite. One big difference is that now the Federal Reserve and other central banks understand stagflation much better. In 1973 it was a puzzling new phenomenon, and no one knew how to think about it. Economists and central bankers of the day had lived through a history in which booming economies brought on rising inflation and sluggish economies brought on rising unemployment. The two maladies didn’t occur simultaneously. (italics added)
This is from Alan S. Blinder, “If We Get a Recession in 2022 or 2023, It’ll Be a Mild One,” Wall Street Journal, April 28, 2022. (April 29 print edition.)
But here’s what Milton Friedman said in his presidential address to the American Economics Association in December 1967:
Let us assume that the monetary authority tries to peg the “market” rate of unemploymentat a level below the “natural” rate. For definiteness, suppose that it takes 3 per cent as the target rate and that the “natural” rate is higher than 3 per cent. Suppose also that we start out at a time when prices have been stable and when unemployment is higher than 3 per cent. Accordingly, the authority increases the rate of monetary growth. This will be expansionary. By making nominal cash balances higher than people desire, it will tend initially to lower interest rates and in this and other ways to stimulate spending. Income and spending will start to rise.
To begin with, much or most of the rise in income will take the form of an increase in output and employment rather than in prices. People have been expecting prices to be stable, and prices and wages have been set for some time in the future on that basis. It takes time for people to adjust to a new state of demand. Producers will tend to react to the initial expansion in aggregate demand by increasing output, employees by working longer hours, and the unemployed, by taking jobs now offered at former nominal wages. This much is pretty standard doctrine.
But it describes only the initial effects. Because selling prices of products typically respond to an unanticipated rise in nominal demand faster than prices of factors of production, real wages received have gone down-though real wages anticipated by employees went up, since employees implicitly evaluated the wages offered at the earlier price level. Indeed, the simultaneous fall ex post in real wages to employers and rise ex ante in real wages to employees is what enabled employment to increase. But the decline ex post in real wages will soon come to affect anticipations. Employees will start to reckon on rising prices of the things they buy and to demand higher nominal wages for the future. “Market” unemployment is below the “natural” level. There is an excess demand for labor so real wages will tend to rise toward their initial level.
Even though the higher rate of monetary growth continues, the rise in real wages will reverse the decline in unemployment, and then lead to a rise, which will tend to return unemployment to its former level. In order to keep unemploymentat its target level of 3 per cent, the monetary authority would have to raise monetary growth still more.
In other words, Milton Friedman, well before the 1973 stagflation, anticipated that one can get “stagflation,” the combination of high unemployment and high inflation.
What misled Alan Blinder is that the economists he studied under, Robert Solow and Paul Samuelson, did not anticipate this combination because they were blinded by their Keynesian Phillips Curve way of thinking.
But that wasn’t the whole universe of economists. Friedman saw it clearly over 5 years before the 1973 stagflation.
Here’s my bio of Milton Friedman in David R. Henderson, ed., The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics. Here’s Kevin D. Hoover’s excellent entry on the Phillips Curve in the Encyclopedia.
READER COMMENTS
Mark Brady
Jun 5 2022 at 6:05pm
James Forder begs to differ in his book Macroeconomics and the Phillips Curve Myth (Oxford University Press, 2014). Online anyone interested can read his posts “The history of the Phillips curve” at http://jamesforder.uk/introduction-to-the-phillips-curve/ and http://jamesforder.uk/more-on-the-phillips-curve-since-macroeconomics-and-the-phillips-curve-myth/, and a great deal more.
James Forder is Andrew Graham Fellow and Tutor in Political Economy at Balliol College, Oxford, and Academic and Research Director at the Institute of Economic Affairs in London.
David Henderson
Jun 5 2022 at 6:46pm
You write:
But notice what he begs to differ with? Namely, the idea that Milton Friedman (and Ned Phelps, if we’re going to be complete) was the lone wolf who saw the problem with the Phillips Curve when no one else did. Forder says a number of people saw the problem. If that’s so, then Blinder is even more wrong than I said.
Mark Brady
Jun 20 2022 at 3:04pm
This is a belated response to your prompt reply to my comment. There’s more to James Forder’s argument than your remarks seem to suggest. I encourage you to read further what he has to say, and I’d interested to read anything more that you might have to say.
Scott Sumner
Jun 5 2022 at 6:30pm
Blinder’s also wrong about the inflation of the 1970s, which was caused by monetary stimulus, not supply shocks.
David Henderson
Jun 5 2022 at 6:48pm
You’re absolutely right. If I recall correctly, I did a numerate analysis in the fall of 1979 when I was the incoming editor of Cato’s Policy Report, showing that the OPEC price increase could account for only about one or two percentage points of one year’s (1974) inflation. So many Keynesians seems to abandon basic numeracy back then.
Rob Rawlings
Jun 5 2022 at 7:34pm
Does Friedman really anticipate stagflation in that quote ? He explains very clearly how attempting to increase employment above the natural level by monetary expansion will fail and be inflationary – but to lead to stagflation wouldn’t employment eventually have to fall below the natural rate ? He doesn’t seem to describe how monetary expansion would cause that to happen. In that quote he explains the inflation bit but not the stagnation.
David Henderson
Jun 7 2022 at 7:58pm
Good point. He doesn’t quite get there in that quote.
What’s missing, and what he did write elsewhere around the same time or at least well before 1973, is that if the Fed cuts the growth rate of the money supply so that inflation falls (but is still positive and above where it was originally), workers, once they have caught on to the preceding high inflation, will now take a given real wage to be lower that it really is because they haven’t adjusted to the somewhat-lower inflation. So you’ll get higher than normal unemployment along with inflation.
Michael Rulle
Jun 6 2022 at 10:32am
I will always remember and enjoy Arnold Kling’s critique of Blinder’s forecast of the deficit spending multiplier—-something like 1.783%. He particularly enjoyed the 3 digits after the decimal. Since then, I could not take Blinder seriously.
Don Boudreaux
Jun 6 2022 at 11:24am
It’s astonishing to me that any economist can reveal without embarrassment – as Blinder does in this WSJ piece – that he or she believes it to be plausible that rapid economic growth causes inflation. How can an increase in output – and especially an increase in output that’s rapid – cause the price level to rise? With stable money, the price level should fall with increases in economic productivity – as George Selgin eloquently explains in his monograph, Less Than Zero. As David suggests, the fact that Blinder seems oblivious to this reality points to the great confusion caused by Keynesianism.
artifex
Jun 6 2022 at 1:57pm
Indeed, RGDP growth is deflationary, but is the fault of thinking otherwise really caused by Keynesianism? It could just be an illusion caused by confounding. Fast RGDP growth in the short run, together with inflation, confounded by NGDP growth. Leading people to think that economic growth is inflationary, even though it’s deflationary.
Mark D Friedman
Jun 10 2022 at 12:45am
When was the last time Blinder made a correct prediction? (asking for a friend).
Comments are closed.