![Timmons on Occupational Licensing](https://www.econlib.org/wp-content/uploads/2024/07/Unknown.jpeg)
Occupational licensing today directly affects more than one in five workers in the United States—up from one in 20 workers in the 1950s. This is nearly twice the fraction of workers belonging to a union and more than 15 times the fraction of workers receiving the federal minimum wage. Although licensing is widespread in the United States, it does not receive the same level of attention as either of these other labor market institutions. Occupational licensing is costly for both consumers and aspiring workers, but results in measurable benefits for existing market practitioners. Occupational licensing persists even though its costs very likely outweigh its benefits.
This is the first paragraph of Edward J. Timmons, “Occupational Licensing,” in David R. Henderson, ed., The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics. It’s a badly needed update to the original article on occupational licensing in the Encyclopedia, “Occupational Licensing” by David S. Young. Young’s article stands up surprisingly well, given that it’s 31 years old. Still, lots has happened, both in policy and in research on the issue. Timmons is on the leading edge of this research.
Another excerpt:
Economists have estimated the effects of occupational licensing on consumers, aspiring workers, and existing practitioners. By restricting consumer choice and limiting the number of providers of licensed services, licensing, economic theory would predict, should increase prices. Research confirms that licensing raises the prices of licensed services by anywhere from 3 to 13%.
Evidence is more mixed on the effects of licensing on the quality of services received by consumers. A few studies looking at licensing of physicians and midwives at the turn of the 20th century find evidence of some benefits for consumers in the form of lower mortality rates. Studies estimating the effects of licensing in the 21st century often find little evidence of benefits for consumers. A recent book published by the Upjohn Institute examining case studies of licensing in the US and Europe reaches the conclusion that licensing is not improving the quality of services delivered to consumers.
It is also important to note that estimating the average effects of licensing on quality may not fully capture losses in access to service from reductions in the number of professionals. This has come to be known as the “Cadillac effect.” Milton Friedman introduced the idea in his 1962 classic, Capitalism and Freedom. The idea is that licensing limits consumers to either purchasing services from providers meeting standards set by licensing boards (Cadillacs), or not purchasing services at all. This may encourage consumers to seek services in the underground economy or incentivize consumers to do the services themselves. Early work by Carrol and Gaston supports the idea that consumers begin to perform more “do-it-yourself” work when licensing limits consumer choice by restricting entry.
Notice in the above that Milton Friedman was one of the skeptics on licensing long before skepticism became popular. I remember being blown way, when I was 17, by his discussion of how we could have good medicine without licensing doctors. As Milton recognized at the time, he took the hardest issue to refute and, at least in my mind, refuted it.
Thanks to Alicia Plemmons, who is one of the leading researchers in the area, for humbly recommending her colleague Edward Timmons as author of the piece and thanks also to Tyler Cowen for taking a quick look.
READER COMMENTS
nobody.really
Jul 22 2024 at 11:48am
It seems a shame not to mention that Adam Smith favored professional licensure:
Adam Smith, The Wealth of Nations (1776), Book V, Chapter I, Part III, Article II. (Smith has another quote on this topic directed specifically at people pursuing advanced offices or trades, but I couldn’t find it.)
Peter
Jul 22 2024 at 12:44pm
I’m no expert on Smith but even in that quote I think he is still limiting it to what we would call skilled trades today, i.e. blacksmiths, doctors, etc, things that in his day mostly had a apprenticeship program. The moden state goes well beyond that and I don’t think Smith would approve having to get a license to do laundry, sweep the floor, or wipe someone’s butt.
We gotten to the point in the US even unskilled labor jobs need licensing. For example here in Hawaii, which I believe routinely tops the chart for most occupational licensing required state, you need a license to be a Walmart greeter.
nobody.really
Jul 22 2024 at 3:11pm
Forget Adam Smith; if that’s true, THAT fact should appear in the encylopedia article! If you have a link for this, please, please share.
Richard W. Fulmer
Jul 22 2024 at 10:39pm
According to the following, the state of Hawaii does not require Walmart greeters to be licensed:
https://search.arc.net/Ns8VfSvP2uj1aV5URAQw
Peter
Jul 24 2024 at 9:57pm
Walmart greeters are considered guards and have to get a guard card like any other guard in this state.
steve
Jul 22 2024 at 1:29pm
You may think Friedman refuted medical licensing for doctors but many others dont think he did. Insurers would just require something similar before they would pay people. It also serves, like board certification, as a kind of safe harbor for the entities that hire physicians. Licensing as it currently exists has issues but we already have issues with bad docs moving from hospital to hospital until they lose their license. Absent licensure they could just keep moving until they retire.
Steve
Jose Pablo
Jul 28 2024 at 8:56am
It would be interesting to have an understanding of why licensing happens to this extent. A positive theory able to explain reality.
According to Timmons, licensing benefits a few at the expense of a majority. Under a majoritarian rule, the political process should make this benefit of the few disappear. A political coalition of the people negatively affected by licensing should be able to pass laws prohibiting the practice. And yet …
So, why is it so? Some possible explanations:
The majority of citizens are not aware of the negative impact of licensing on them. After all the alternative reality without licensing that doesn’t exist can’t be observed.
The majority of citizens “buy” the argument that they need licensing to be protected from malpractice.
The few benefiting from licensing are much better organized politically and/or are bigger donors. They can successfully lobby the political power, which fails to protect the interest of a majority of constituents
All of the above
Comments are closed.