Price Controls with Fixed Supply

Most economists oppose price controls, especially those following a disaster or some other unexpected event (commonly called “anti price-gouging legislation”).  However, UMASS–Amherst economist Isabella Weber objects.  She tweets: “One of the problems with [the supply and demand diagram] is that it is missing a crucial dimension: time. When it comes to price gouging in emergencies, that’s a pretty big problem.”  This tweet has spawned numerous responses from various economists, most pointing out to her that the supply and demand model does take into account time: the x-axis is properly labeled “quantity per unit of time.” (My late, great PhD professor, Walter Williams, would deduct points from anyone who wrote the x-axis as just quantity).  Furthermore, both supply and demand become more elastic over time.

These objections are correct, but I think they miss the claim that Weber is making as well as the larger, economic mistake she is making.  Weber is arguing that price controls do not have the negative effects of deadweight loss when the supply of a good is fixed and the timeline for it to become unfixed is long.  Let’s analyze her claim first on its own merits and then from a richer economic lens.

Weber is approaching this problem from the perspective of Marshallian welfare economics where the performance of a market is judged by whether or not total surplus (the gains from trade to the producer plus the gains from trade to the consumer) is maximized.  Calculating these gains from trade is fairly easy: for the consumer, it is simply the difference between what a consumer is willing to pay for each unit consumed and what they have to pay for each unit consumed.  For the producer, the gains from trade are the difference between the price the seller receives for each good sold and what they are willing to sell for each good sold.  The total surplus (total gains from trade) are thus consumer surplus (consumer gains from trade) plus producer surplus (producer gains from trade).  

Two very important things to note: 1) how much surplus is generated in the market depends on the quantity exchanged in the market.  If the quantity exchanged falls, total surplus will fall (and vice versa)  2) how surplus is distributed between consumers and producers depends on the price.  Generally speaking, a higher price implies lower consumer surplus and more producer surplus (all else held equal).

From a strict, Marshallian welfare-economic perspective, Weber’s claim is correct.  When supply is fixed (i.e., perfectly inelastic) and there is no time to either increase supply or get the curve more elastic, then price gouging legislation will not result in deadweight loss.  Since the quantity does not change, putting a price ceiling simply shifts gains from trade from the producer to the consumer.  Total surplus in the market does not change; there is no deadweight loss since the quantity in the market does not change.

However, from a broader, richer economic perspective, where we think about how people actually behave when faced with different choices, her point is incorrect.  Price controls will still lead to shortages as the quantity demanded exceeds the quantity supplied.  While there is no deadweight loss, the costs of those shortages still arise: queuing, hoarding, etc.  Furthermore, since the price being kept artificially low disincentivizes the supply curve from becoming elastic and/or growing, the costs of price ceilings persist longer than they would otherwise.  These are very real costs and, taking them into account, shows that even given fixed supply, price controls make everyone worse off.

So, by comparison of these two states (price ceilings where producer surplus is transferred to the consumer but the consumer and producer bear much higher total costs over a longer period of time, or prices rise, consumer surplus is transferred to the producer, but these extra costs are not imposed), price ceilings still incur undesirable effects, especially so following a disaster.

And there are many other possible objections as well.  In a conversation with me on Facebook, retired Texas Tech economist Michael Giberson pointed out that there is no particular economic justification to prefer consumers over producers in this (or any other) exchange.  Another is that there is no reason to think that the distribution of goods to the consumer will be any more “just.”

Furthermore, as Kevin Corcoran recently reminded us, we want to avoid the one-stage thinking permeating Weber’s claim.  Price control legislation has long lasting effects by changing the incentives for suppliers against preparing for a disaster.  As economist Benjamin Zycher shows, price controls in wartime discourage producers from stockpiling war materiel in peacetime.  The same holds true for non-defense goods.  Stockpiling is costly; it takes away storage space from goods that can be more quickly sold.  For firms to stockpile, they need to have the expectation of higher prices in the future.  If they know they will not be able to charge higher prices in the future, then the cost of stockpiling will be higher than the benefits.  Firms will keep fewer goods on hand, so that when the disaster does strike, fewer goods will be available for the aftermath.  The best time to end price controls is before a disaster.  The second best time is now.

In sum, Isabella Weber’s tweet is mathematically correct but economically incorrect.  It is internally consistent and logical, but contains no economics.  We must always look beyond just the model to the reality the model is simulating.

 


Jon Murphy is an assistant professor of economics at Nicholls State University.

READER COMMENTS

Don
Oct 24 2024 at 10:30am

In addition to the dynamic considerations you explain (quite well), there is also the issue of allocative inefficiency resulting from price ceilings. That is, if price is not used to ration who gets the (fixed quantity of) goods, then generally, the goods won’t wind up in the highest-value uses, unless there’s a robust secondary market. Zero deadweight loss in Weber’s special case is a lower bound, if miraculously the scarce goods end up in the possession of exactly those consumers who would have paid the most for them, if price had been used to ration them.

So Weber is (arguably) making an even more basic error than the one you point out. If it were a student paper, I’d give it a C.

Jon Murphy
Oct 24 2024 at 10:54am

Very good point.

I’d say you’re a more generous grader than I am.  I’d lean toward a D or F.  She’s missing the economic insights.

David Seltzer
Oct 24 2024 at 11:56am

Jon: Interesting. As quantity supplied is inelastic, so is quantity demanded. Recently, John Cochrane wrote in praise of price gouging wherein his choices were pay high price for the last motel room available for his family or sleep in their car overnight. In terms of time, a few days later motel room supply increased as did consumer surplus.

Jon Murphy
Oct 24 2024 at 12:08pm

As quantity supplied is inelastic, so is quantity demanded.

Please forgive me for putting on my “professor” hat, but what you said is incorrect.

The supply curve (or demand curve) can be elastic/inelastic.  Quantity supplied and quantity demanded are not elastic/inelastic.

Elasticity is defined as the (% change in quantity/% change in price).*  It’s a measure of how responsive the supplier/demander is to a change in price; how much quantity supplied/quantity demanded changes as price changes.

So, the elasticity of one does not imply anything about the elasticity of the other.

*More pricisely, it’s elasticity= (P/Q)(dQ/dP)

Craig
Oct 24 2024 at 1:24pm

” “One of the problems with [the supply and demand diagram] is that it is missing a crucial dimension: time. When it comes to price gouging in emergencies, that’s a pretty big problem.”  This tweet has spawned numerous responses from various economists, most pointing out to her that the supply and demand model does take into account time”

Plus even if the x-axis weren’t labelled with time, the price paid is often thought of as the nominal price charged by the store, but in reality the price paid by the consumer includes whatever incidental costs are incurred to engage in the transaction, whether gas to go to the store or additional time spent in a queue to wait for a rationed product.

It IS often said ‘time is money’ so I do agree with you Professor Murphy that demand does take into account time even beyond the reasons you note.

Dylan
Oct 24 2024 at 3:00pm

First, thanks for the lesson, I don’t think in any of my economics classes I ever picked up that “quantity per unit of time” was the correct label. I recall differences between short-run and long-run S&D curves, but I can’t recall ever seeing time explicitly labeled on either axis. I obviously needed your econ prof!

Still…I imagine the scenario that Prof. Weber had in mind is something more along the lines of this. Let’s say you’re captain of your very own spaceship. Unfortunately, you’ve just had several catastrophic failures in a row, and lost all of your oxygen as a result. Luckily, in the vast emptiness of space, you happen to be right next to a big ship with plenty of oxygen to spare! But then, again unfortunately, the captain of that ship is a heartless and calculating sort, who agrees to allow you on board only after you sign a binding agreement for all your current and future assets. Quick, you have 1 minute to decide before you pass out.

Is the captain gouging? Should international space courts honor that contract?

Jon Murphy
Oct 24 2024 at 3:22pm

I don’t think she had a scenerio like that in mind.  It’s quite different from the situation she tweets about.  Her scenerio is about an individual getting the air regardless; it’s just a matter of price.  The answer to the question posed by you is not one of price controls but one of contract law (it’s been a while, but I don’t think such contracts signed under duress are enforceable).

 I don’t think in any of my economics classes I ever picked up that “quantity per unit of time” was the correct label.

I doubt many do use that label.  I never encountered it until my PhD micro class with Dr Williams.

Dylan
Oct 24 2024 at 5:42pm

I was being a little tongue in cheek about that scenario, I don’t think she had something exactly like that in mind. But, given the part quoted (I don’t have a Twitter account, so if there are follow-ups that go into more detail, I can’t see them), I thought that was directionally the way she way thinking. Basically, supply is fixed, it is an emergency so these are life and death commodities, and there are heartless capitalists out there that will take advantage of the situation and would rather let someone die of thirst if another person will give them an extra hundred so they can water their lawn. Maybe I’m reading too much into it, but those are the assumptions I typically see that underlie support for anti-gouging laws.

As you rightly point out, these laws don’t actually keep the price lower, in fact they drastically raise prices, just along a different dimension than pure monetary costs. What gets me is, for some reason, in emergency type situations, people seem to much prefer rationing via time than by money. It’s not rational, but I’m not sure what we can do about it short of changing human nature? This paper is a good try though!

Mactoul
Oct 25 2024 at 1:51am

I don’t think such contracts signed under duress are enforceable

Is it an intrinsic feature of contracts themselves or does it pertain to American law?

Jon Murphy
Oct 25 2024 at 6:11am

That’s a question better left to a lawyer. I don’t know the one and outs of contract law to answer.

Matthias
Oct 26 2024 at 3:16am

Why do you need to make a contract enforceable? As far as I can tell, that’s only necessary, if the payment is still outstanding?

If you hand over the money, and I hand over the oxygen, then afterwards you’d need to go and sue me to get the money back. I’m not sure contract enforceability helps you there?

The threshold for a court to forcibly revert the transaction are much higher than for them to void a contract where payment is still outstanding.

Dylan
Oct 26 2024 at 7:15am

In my hypothetical I said all current and future assets, meaning you owe all of your future output until death. Plus, I figure you probably wouldn’t have everything you own on you in your spaceship, so there’s probably still something to enforce even with current assets.

Jon Murphy
Oct 26 2024 at 8:36am

If the contract is unenforceable, you sure to get your money back

Bill Conerly
Oct 24 2024 at 6:34pm

Elasticity is an economic phenomenon, not a technical characteristic of a product. I never heard that in an economics class, but I talk to my business clients in a number of industries about how much inventory they carry, how rapidly that can spin up extra capacity, to what extent they could delay delivery to some customers to immediately serve others in great need.

And when supply chains were in great distress a couple of years ago, we discussed alternative products, services and labor that could substitute for the stuff that was hard to get. Most products have substitutes of some type, and the substitutes may have greater elasticity.

And price gouging laws clearly reduce elasticity of supply.

David Henderson
Oct 24 2024 at 6:40pm

You write:

From a strict, Marshallian welfare-economic perspective, Weber’s claim is correct.

Are you sure? I admit that I haven’t read Marshall since graduate school and, even then, I read only selected passages. But it’s hard for me to believe that Marshall missed both the misallocation among demanders (which you also missed) and the cost of queueing. Have you checked Marshall?

Jon Murphy
Oct 24 2024 at 7:04pm

I haven’t checked Marshall, but I would be surprised if he made the mistake Weber makes. But the logic of how surplus is derived in his framework implies no dead weight loss from perfectly inelastic supply. I recall Bryan Caplan discussing that in grad school, and at least it’s discussed on the Wikipedia page on consumer surplus

Comments are closed.

RECENT POST

At the recent vice-presidential debate between Senator J.D. Vance and Governor Tim Walz, both leaders emphasized that families are America's backbone. However, they erred in their approach by suggesting that more government involvement could solve families' challenges. From expanding the child tax credit to advocating ...

Read More

  4. Econ Log EconLog, run by the Library of Economics and Liberty, includes various contributors sharing ideas on economic theory, public policy, and classical liberal views. This blog offers a place for lively debate and different opinions. (bold in original) This is from Anja Finegan, "The Top Econ...

Read More

Most economists oppose price controls, especially those following a disaster or some other unexpected event (commonly called “anti price-gouging legislation”).  However, UMASS–Amherst economist Isabella Weber objects.  She tweets: “One of the problems with [the supply and demand diagram] is that it is missing...

Read More