First, let’s talk about spurious scholarly journals. The Financial Times reports on a palace revolt of academics against a private publisher who made some changes to a presumably (and understandably) unprofitable academic journal (“Academics Boycott Wiley Gender Journal After ‘Anti-Woke’ Shift,” March 15, 2024):
Academics are boycotting a leading gender studies journal owned by New York-listed publisher Wiley after its editors and policies were changed in what they characterise as an “anti-woke” drive against radical views in the pursuit of profits.
Nearly 500 advisers, reviewers, contributors and readers have written resignation letters to Wiley in protest at the “mainstreaming” of the Gender, Work and Organization journal by changing its aims, including the removal of references to queer theory on its website.
A description of the journal on Wiley’s website explains what it is supposed to be after the changes:
Issues of critical importance as Gender, Work & Organization moves forward include feminist knowledge and practice, feminist philosophies and praxis, diversity, intersectionality, transnational, postcolonial, and decolonial feminisms, feminist ecology, postfeminist humanism/posthumanist feminism, embodiment, affect and organising, gendered power, resistance and activism, gender and global labour markets, critical analyses of neoliberalism, postfeminism, femininities and heroic versus post-heroic leadership approaches.
It does not look very scholarly, does it? It is at least unclear how this sort of discourse advances the search for truth and our knowledge of how society works. It is of course desirable that anybody who wants to defend the positions of Gender, Work & Organization be free to do it, with his own resources or those he levies among voluntary partners and donors.
Wiley’s incentives (and its competitors’) are to make the most profits by supplying what consumers are willing to pay for. Similarly, we can understand the incentives of academics—especially those who defend obtuse theories of the flat-earth type—to deal with government bureaucracies rather than with private firms: it is incomparably easier for them to be subsidized by invisible taxpayers. Why can’t these academics create and sell, or otherwise finance, their own journals? The question is all the more relevant as their academic salaries and perks are already partly or, for those in public universities, totally subsidized by governments, which in large part explains how academic journals can get free articles.
Second, let’s put these issues in an educational perspective. Education is, as many goods more or less, what economists call an “experience good”: you cannot know how much you will enjoy it, if you enjoy it at all, without actually consuming it. You could not know before learning Latin how you would enjoy reading Virgil in his language. You could not know before learning economics how many secrets of the social world you would discover from reading (and understanding) Anthony de Jasay or John Hicks or so many others.
Hence the idea that it is good to educate children at an age where the opportunity cost of learning is low—this low cost being partially explained by the plasticity of their minds. Even in the case of young adults, who should of course not be forced to be educated, it is a good idea to try and persuade them to continue their education, if they have the required mental capacity and the opportunity cost of their time is not too high. In these conditions, anyone will nearly certainly, later in life, be happy he (or she) learned more. At any event, it must be easier, if one later so desires, to forget what one has learned, than to learn from scratch what one has no idea of.
One potential problem is that the suppliers of education (the producers of education services) have their own self-interests and incentives. They try to “maximize their profits” in the pecuniary sense and also possibly for the pleasure of ideological activism. These two motivations explain their greed for trade unions armed with extraordinary privileges from the state, and for conventional tenure, too. The danger is that they will deliver education not according to what consumers will later wish they had learned, but according to their interests as producers. So education becomes a club or cartel of producers instead of a market for the services that children’s parents or young adults want. For sure, other motivations may be present like a teaching “vocation” and a sense of duty, but they will be overruled if more practical incentives counter them.
Any economist will know that competition is the way to avoid the club-of-producers danger. If many suppliers of education (schools, universities, teachers from different schools of thought) compete, none of them will have the power to exploit consumers. It’s like for “ordinary” trade: the consumer is unlikely to be exploited if he can buy his wares from several sources and no supplier is regulated out of the market. Protectionism is a way for suppliers, assisted by the secular (coercive) hand of the state, to transform international trade into a club of national producers. Similarly, government regulation and subsidization are the means by which education suppliers can transform their market into a club of producers. Education then becomes what the educators want to propagandize, which will typically align with what politicians and bureaucrats (the ones who write the checks) want their subjects to learn.
Isn’t this what education has become? So-called scholarly journals such as Gender, Work & Organization are one illustration in higher education. They would not exist if taxpayers were not forced to pay educators to spend their time reading these spurious journals, writing in them, and pushing their institutions’ libraries to subscribe. Or, more exactly, these journals would be webzines published on private websites by eccentric theorists. It is good that eccentrics exist (see John Stuart Mill’s On Liberty). Who knows, they may be right. But they should compete on the free market of ideas without extorting subsidies and other privileges.
*****************************
The featured image of this post, created by OpenAI’s DALL-E, represents the sad but fictional story of a Professor of Queer Theory (he could also be a DEI university administrator) who was laid off after a reduction in government subsidies to “higher education.” Fortunately, he was able to find a job as a McDonald’s burger flipper, upgrading his life from exploiting his fellow humans to serving them.
READER COMMENTS
Andrea Mays
Mar 19 2024 at 1:43pm
“So education becomes a club or cartel of producers instead of a market for the services that children’s parents or young adults want.”
The university (if you will allow me a moment to personify an institution) has its own preferences, and it serves THEM first, students sometimes. My hypothesis would be private schools which charge high tuition (I have taught at two of them) have to attract customers in a way low tuition public universities (I have taught at several of them) do not. At small private schools, they know who the customer is and attempt to serve that population. No so much competition at the public U’s. (Particularly at the high ranking public schools like UC Berkeley and U Michigan, there is excess demand for seats at the table— for a low-cost but highly rated school.)
If it comes to that for me, I can cook mean steaks or walk dogs!
Pierre Lemieux
Mar 19 2024 at 5:50pm
Andrea: As organizations, universities certainly have goals. I would say that their goals are more to satisfy the demands of those who write the biggest checks, which are often the subsidizing governments. This removes most of the market constraints (the market test), which then allows the producers (university administrators and professors) to largely supply what they want and what their government sponsors want. Indeed, small private colleges would seem to offer a way out–but competing with suppliers partly subsidized (or even more subsidized) by the taxpayer is a tall order.
Laurentian
Mar 19 2024 at 6:01pm
Mill only supported eccentrics as long as they don’t cause the spread of “barbarism” as defined by him.
Pierre Lemieux
Mar 19 2024 at 6:36pm
Laurentian: Can you elaborate?
Laurentian
Mar 19 2024 at 7:11pm
Mill is pretty explicit in his writings that nothing he writes is meant to apply to “barbarians”.
And how does one define barbarian? Mill’s decades long involvement with the East India Compamy doesn’t fit in with modern ideas of modernity.
Pierre Lemieux
Mar 20 2024 at 3:01pm
Laurentian: You raise an interesting and difficult question. Mill does not carefully distinguish individuals, “nations,” and governments–not only in the paragraph of On Liberty from which you quoted, but also in “On the Treatment of Barbarous Nations.” But there is little question in my mind, and in the minds of all classical liberals I know, that there is no moral equivalence between those who share an ethics of reciprocity between natural equals and the barbarians who don’t in any way; indeed, this would define “barbarians.” We may clearly say, for example, that ISIS terrorists are barbarians; and, at a lower degree, Maduro or Putin and their minions. It does not mean that they should be treated like dogs (like they treat their opponents) when captured. It is worth reading Buchanan’s little book, Why I, Too, Am Not a Conservative, and my review of the book, where this issue is raised.
Mactoul
Mar 19 2024 at 9:56pm
How much of education, even in STEM, survive under the model of consumer sovereignty?
Plenty of STEM research, and here I speak from experience, is as bizarre as woke studies.
Education is one of the ways a (political order) perpetuates itself. Students aren’t consumers merely but future citizens. Hence the woke studies would continue under the woke regime irrespective of what consumers might want.
Pierre Lemieux
Mar 20 2024 at 2:36pm
Mactoul: “Consume” in economic analysis means to benefit from: one consumes an apple by eating, a book or a journal by reading it or keeping it, (the services of) a house by living in it, and indeed even a citizenship by crossing the border at will (this is why many people make a lot of efforts, i.e., pay a lot to get a second one). Contrary to much sociological mumbo jumbo, economic analysis with economic concepts has shown to be very useful for understanding the social world.
Jose Pablo
Mar 20 2024 at 7:43pm
If the STEM research, no matters how bizarre, has any value, why shouldn’t it survive under the consumer sovereignty model?
Even if it takes a very long time to monetize the “bizarre STEM research”. Afterall a 2003 Romanee Conti Grand Cru has survived the consumer sovereignty model despite the 20+ years required to sell it to final consumers.
Even if the risk of the bizarre STEM research ending in nothing useful is pretty high. Afterall the pharmaceutical industry does exist.
Now, I understand why it is way easier to convince a bureaucrat with no skin in the game to spend other people’s money financing a “bizarre STEM research” than to convince a return oriented investor to do the same.
Precisely because of that …
Monte
Mar 20 2024 at 3:10am
Doesn’t Mancur Olson’s collective action theory address situations like this, where minority groups “bound together by concentrated selective incentives” manage to dominate the majority by agitating for change and triggering a tsunami of policy changes on a grand scale?
Pierre Lemieux
Mar 20 2024 at 8:00am
Monte: That’s a good point. However, I am not sure that “bound together by concentrated selective incentives” is a phrase that comes from Olson. His theory is that small groups (with concentrated interests) will be easier to organize notably through selective individual incentives (social events, group insurance benefits, and such). In our case here, it could work this way: We have a small group of woke activists with common interests and the main entrepreneur who gets them together for collective action is the government through selective incentives for subsidized jobs in educational institutions as well as opportunities for government research grants and consulting jobs. Government agents and politicians do this because it allows them to increase their own personal influence, power, salaries, and perks.
Monte
Mar 20 2024 at 11:27am
Thanks for the clarification. The “bound together by concentrated selective incentives” comment actually came from a reviewer’s interpretation of Olson’s theory as propounded in his book, The Logic of Collective Action. But your interpretation is more accurate, I believe.
I suppose Gender, Work, and Organization (and other “spurious scholarly journals” of its kind) could technically be considered a public good that is foisted upon consumers of education resulting in a negative externality in the form of mental pollution?
Ralph Soule
Mar 20 2024 at 10:36am
I’m a board member of an academic journal. That’s a sample size of one, but our publisher (not Wiley) doesn’t tell us how to describe the purpose of the journal. That is solely a decision made by the board.
Pierre Lemieux
Mar 20 2024 at 3:06pm
Ralph: That’s a good point. I didn’t mean to say that the text was from Wiley. But they do have to accept it on their website and to agree to publish the journal. Indeed, if I read the FT story correctly, Wiley removed, or persuaded the journal to remove, “queer theory” from the new description.
Knut P. Heen
Mar 20 2024 at 11:47am
The change cannot have been that large. The last issue has an article about becoming a mother in neoliberal academia. I wondered what planet had a neoliberal academia and it turned out to be Italy.
Pierre Lemieux
Mar 22 2024 at 11:22am
Knut: LOL. Perhaps that’s part of what they know and that nobody else knows.
Monte
Mar 20 2024 at 7:27pm
Of more dubious acclaim, we have Hypatia: A Journal of Feminist Philosophy and Journal of Poetry Therapy, both of which were caught up in the infamous Grievance Studies Affair:
I’m not questioning the feasibility of the notions they subscribe to, just pointing out that the cognitive biases of the people who make up the editorial teams of these types of journals seem particularly vulnerable to intelligent nonsense.
Jim Glass
Mar 20 2024 at 7:36pm
I’d think the gangs and drug warlords fighting to take over by destroying the state in El Salvador and Ecuador, and succeeding in Haiti, are good contemporary examples.
Bringing to mind a famous example from history, with Machiavelli praising the actions of the great and infamous Cesare Borgia, debated ever since: When the Borgias conquered the Romagna region of Italy they sought to obtain with it a prosperous, happy population, willing to pay tribute. But they found a state of anarchy, the people driven into fear and poverty by barbarous brigands – no tribute from them! What to do?
Cesare first sent one of his must trusted and ruthless associates, Remirro de Orco, to clean up the place. Which Remirro and his minions did, making the roads safe, enforcing peace between factions, and even building public works — via the tools of torture, public executions and, um, protection fees to pay for it all. Yet the people, ever unsatisfied, continued to complain. So…
Cesare then rode in with troops, and — declaring himself shocked! shocked! by the injustices he found — he cut off Remirro’s head and put it on a spike as a warning to other would-be wrongdoers … leaving the people “appeased and stupefied”. Also safe, prosperous, paying tribute, and happy to pay it to him.
So can we say Cesare was: A) A sociopath despot who killed his own closest associates for personal gain? or B) An enlightened ruler who brought his people to safety and prosperity the fastest way possible with the least total violence? or C) Both?
Niccolo’s story is stylized of course, and historians have spent a lot more words on it than he did, developing the fuller facts and backstory. But reading modern economic tomes documenting the historical development of states (like Why Nations Fail and Violence and Social Orders) can give the impression that there may be more merit in his praise of Cesare than a lot of people will be comfortable with.
Jose Pablo
Mar 20 2024 at 10:37pm
The Cesarean approach has undergone significant improvements since then. The American Constitution of 1789 comes to mind.
It appears that the more constrained the ruler, the better it is for “his” slaves (sorry, I meant “his” people).
One might be tempted to hope that the welfare of the ruler’s subjects follows a continuous function with the level of restraint of the ruler as the independent variable, reaching a maximum at the extreme end of the spectrum corresponding to infinite restraint (also known as anarchism).
However, it could also be the case that the maximum welfare of the ruler’s subjects is attained at a lower level of ruler’s restraint. This would be unfortunate because it would imply that the highest level of well-being “his” people can achieve is limited to the level of well-being of slaves (like people in the Romania region under Cesar, slaves also used to find safety and prosperity under the protection of benevolent masters).
Vivek Moorthy
Mar 20 2024 at 9:12pm
The author of this article has ignored some fundamental maladies pertaining to higher education, specifically grade inflation and the proliferation of expensive degrees which students “buy” by paying high fees with very little risk of failing. Simple minded consumer and market analogies are highly misleading when applied to education since students are not just consumers shopping for the best product (university). They are also a product whose quality needs to be examined and certified. That process calls for grade regulation of both public and private universities. The author should check out the website gradeinflation.com In its earlier versions, this website had a very illuminating chart documenting the steady rise in grades from the 1930s to recent decades in USA across both public and private universities, Ivy League and non Ivy League universities, regular universities and community colleges. Grade inflation was highest at the Ivy Leagues. The worst culprit was Harvard where at one time the average grade was A minus. The solution is not to cap the fees, as UK did, leading to a flood of foreign students who were charged more than local ones, but to mandate that grading be on a full range with some required fails in very course. That will hit hard at the demand for reputed but dubious degrees and the willingness to pay high fees for them. Merely cutting subsidies for higher education, which certainly have contributed to junk research, and led to an excess of publications even in STEM subjects, is not enough. Anyone who wants to read a detailed essay I wrote over a decade ago on the links between student feed back and grades is welcome to mail me at ep.vivekmoorthyATgmail.com Treating students as consumers has led to a proliferation of junk sub fields and woke departments. Merely cutting subsidies for higher education will not rectify its maladies.
Pierre Lemieux
Mar 22 2024 at 11:43am
Vivek: Thanks for this comment. My post was not intended as an exhaustive analysis of the education market. But with due respect, here is a question. You write:
Who will be the regulator, Donald Trump (and the political appointees he hires and the bureaucrats who obey the latter) or Joe Biden (and the political appointees he hires and the bureaucrats who obey the latter)?
Jose Pablo
Mar 22 2024 at 7:39pm
Pierre, a call for regulation normally means that “somebody has to forcefully resolve this issue the way I think it should be resolved”.
When regulation doesn’t work as intended (so always) the problem is not with regulation but with the fact that the whole thing was not regulated by me.
Like with the planned economy. The problem is not with planned economy “per se” the problem is always that the economy wasn’t planned by me. So it is always worth to give it another try.
James R Glass
Mar 23 2024 at 7:42pm
A quick peek at the scope of things …
https://retractionwatch.com/2024/03/23/weekend-reads-more-retractions-at-columbia-an-epidemic-of-scientific-fraud-when-articles-cite-retracted-papers/
There is an Econ journal in there.
Jim Glass
Apr 5 2024 at 5:41pm
This may be late but is just published today:
A good look at the the economics (and quality) of Physics Scholarly Journals and PhD programs, by one who has spent decades “successfully” getting through them…
https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=LKiBlGDfRU8
Comments are closed.