Prices on the real estate market in Los Angeles County confirm elementary economic theory. The economically illiterates seem surprised. See “Rent Rose by 10 Percent Across L.A. Country After Fires. That’s Illegal,” Washington Post, January 23, 2025. The Wall Street Journal writes (“After the Fires, Bidding Wars and Cutthroat Demand Take Over L.A.’s Rental Market,” January 16, 2025):
Renters are facing bidding wars and inflated prices, with some offering to pay above the listed rent or multiple months upfront. Landlords are taking advantage of the situation, raising concerns about price gouging.
On a free market in ordinary times, both suppliers and demanders are “price gougers.” Note that the expression has no analytical usefulness (it does not help understand the social world) and no relevance to an ethics of reciprocity between free individuals. The suppliers try to get as high a price as possible given the constraint of competition. The demanders on their side try to get as low a price as possible given that many of them are bidding it up like in an invisible auction.
On a free market, every price is the result of “gouging” from both the suppliers and the demanders. It is in emergencies that we see this more clearly. The supply of some good or service (say housing) is suddenly reduced—by the fires in Los Angeles County. Consumers, whose demand has not changed, face fewer apartments for rent or houses for sale than they want. The ones who attach more value to housing in the affected market—say, people whose employment place is in the vicinity or who have children in a local school—will bid up rents and house prices. Others will prefer to move to a smaller place or with their parents or friends, or to move farther away. In the short run, the supply of housing is fixed, so a rise in prices is how, in a free market, the available supply gets distributed. The consumers are the ones who bid up the prices. The suppliers obtain a windfall, as consumers get one when building activity is high (or when economic conditions suddenly favor their own businesses).
In the longer run, price increases will bring new housing suppliers in the market. By trying to profit from higher prices, “gouging¨” suppliers will gradually increase supply and push prices down. Note the crucial role of free-market prices: they signal both the intensity of demand among consumers and the cost of supply in terms of what the required resources (industrial land, labor, etc.) would produce elsewhere in the economy. (See the always interesting Ryan Bourne and Sophia Bagley’s “Gov. Newsom’s Price Controls Will Slow LA’s Recovery,” Substack, January 15, 2025.)
To the price mechanism, two alternatives or a mix of them exist: a permanent shortage—meaning the price is good but the shelves are empty—or some authority giving orders. A third alternative is tribal poverty. On price controls and shortages, think of the old Soviet Union, where the non-nomenklatura buyer faced a 10-year waiting list to buy a car, or the Stockholm housing market, where the waiting for a rent-controlled apartment is 8 to 10 years.
When market prices are capped by government, a free black market partially takes over for consumers who prefer to have the good rather than forego it and for suppliers who choose to sell at a higher price—especially since, at the previous price, they have more customers than what they have to sell.
To understand these conclusions, only basic economics is needed. Business people get an intuitive understanding of supply and demand, or else they don’t remain long in the market. There is nothing like actually learning the elementary theory of supply and demand: a demand curve slopes downward, a supply curve (generally) upward. Quantity demanded is read along the demand curve, and quantity supplied along the supply curve. When an emergency situation decreases supply, it’s the consumers who are doing the “gouging,” that is, the bidding; if there were no consumers, no price would be bid up. Imagine an auction where no buyer shows up.
The Washington Post story mentions the California Attorney General who, from the height of his economic ignorance and with power signs in his eyes, supports another system than individual liberty:
On Wednesday, California Attorney General Rob Bonta (D) announced charges against a real estate agent for allegedly attempting to price-gouge a couple who lost their home in the Eaton Fire. … The charge could carry a fine of up to $10,000 and one year in jail.
“These predators are looking at the disaster with dollar signs in their eyes,” Bonta said at a Jan. 16 news conference.
******************************
READER COMMENTS
MarkW
Jan 30 2025 at 10:32am
Even in the short run, housing supply really isn’t fixed. For a high enough price, a lot of spare bedrooms could come into the market.
Pierre Lemieux
Jan 30 2025 at 11:10am
Mark: Good point! I agree and, while writing, I wondered whether I should elaborate on this. (One can always elaborate on virtually every single word.) I would have noted that it depends on how short is the short run. Except for temporary accommodation with family or friends, the supply of housing is literally fixed 24 hours after the supply shock. Perhaps after a few days, if the price is high enough, some will have readied a spare bedroom and advertised it for rent. And so forth.
David Seltzer
Jan 30 2025 at 12:39pm
Pierre: Timely post. I related the following story to Jon Murphy on a call yesterday. My friend’s parents live in L.A. They evacuated. Fortunately their home didn’t burn. They went to a hotel to get a room. The price(s) for hotel rooms increased within minutes from $400 per night to $1000. Why? a bidding war broke out on the spot for a few remaining rooms. Wall Street aphorism: There are two sides to a market kid! As an aside. During the recent housing run up, Homes in our neighborhood often sold for prices substantially above published asking prices. It was not uncommon to see several people at open houses bidding up prices. Homes often sold the same day they were listed.
Jose Pablo
Jan 30 2025 at 2:36pm
It was not uncommon to see several people at open houses bidding up prices. Homes often sold the same day they were listed.
People are naturally drawn to stories like these that capture public attention (not criticizing David, just acknowledging this after your comment). And yet, such anecdotes are ultimately irrelevant. The only thing that matters, in terms of the number of families housed, is that the home was sold. The price at which it was sold or how quickly it changed hands is entirely inconsequential in the short run. And higher prices can only be beneficial in the long run—at least if the goal is to increase housing availability.
Moreover, if the selling family remains in the area, even the sale itself has no impact on the number of families accommodated locally. The secondary housing market is beneficial primarily because:
a) It provides a reliable price signal that helps other economic agents make informed decisions.
b) It ensures liquidity, reducing the risk and burden associated with building or owning a new home.
Interfering with housing prices or the liquidity of the secondary market can only make it more difficult for new homes to enter the market. And yet, the Attorney General seems to think he knows better…
Jose Pablo
Jan 30 2025 at 1:01pm
I believe cases like the one involving the California Attorney General illustrate (once again) the concept of “that which is seen and that which is not seen.”
Market prices are visible—they are “seen.” But if you suppress them in some way, the market still needs to clear. That doesn’t change. As a result of this need, an alternative form of pricing—one that is less visible— has to emerge. It will be making lines, rely on personal connections with the owner or the public official allocating housing, or simply already be an existing tenant.
These “unseen prices” ultimately leave the same number of people unable to secure housing, as shifting from one pricing mechanism to another does not change the available supply—at least in the short run, assuming supply is perfectly inelastic.
What the Attorney General fails to recognize (surprisingly he should be smarter than that) is that there is another couple—let’s call them Couple B—who is also in need of housing and willing to pay more for the apartment. Perhaps, like Couple A, they too have lost their home in the fire. The Attorney General is not advocating from one more couple having a house. He is advocating for Couple A getting the house instead of couple B.
Unfortunately, most voters only see Couple A. They do not see Couple B. Even more concerning is that the political system incentivizes the Attorney General to side with the more visible Couple A rather than the unseen and now homeless Couple B.
The real tragedy is that the Attorney General may very well have read and understood Bastiat’s argument. Yet, when faced with political incentives and personal interests, he chooses to act otherwise and cause harm in the pursuit of his own benefit. You can not expect any improvement in housing market efficiency without changing the incentives of the political system.
Andrea Mays
Jan 30 2025 at 1:51pm
It is interesting how much visibility the AG and DA’s search for price gougers is getting, compared to the search for and prosecution of looters.
Pierre Lemieux
Jan 30 2025 at 2:43pm
Andrea: Interesting point! These statocrats are the worst looters.