I’m hardly the first to point out that many people can earn graduate degrees in economics without actually absorbing or understanding the economic way of thinking. As is often the case, Twitter (the platform I still refuse to call X) has risen to the occasion to provide an example. In this case, the subject is the Irish economist Phillip Pilkington, who graciously provides an example of what happens when you confuse an increase in supply with an increase in quantity supplied.
On this occasion, Pilkington tweeted out:
THE CHART YIMBY KIDS DON’T WANT YOU TO SEE:
House prices and new construction are POSITIVELY correlated. I.e. when there is more supply prices are rising and when there is less they are falling. The OPPOSITE of the YIMBY argument.
I actually wrote an entire post a year ago specifically addressing this elementary error, but I’ll try to briefly summarize the point I made back then.
Supply, roughly, refers to how much capacity there is to make something. Quantity supplied refers to how much sellers will provide at a given price. New construction isn’t an increase in supply, it’s an increase in the quantity supplied. YIMBY’s don’t argue that we need to increase the quantity of housing supplied, the argument is that we need to increase the housing supply. That is, we need to increase the capacity to produce more housing. Partly this could be done by means of new building methods and technologies, like the modular housing methods that are described in this post. But right now, there is a massive amount of low-hanging fruit available to increase the housing supply in the form of deregulation – eliminating minimum lot sizes, repealing bans on multi-unit housing, reforming zoning laws, that sort of thing. Changes like this will increase the capacity to build housing, which is what is meant by an increase in supply.
Without changes in policy to allow the housing supply to increase, the supply curve stays fixed. And if the supply curve is fixed, but demand is increasing, then as the demand curve shifts to the right, the equilibrium price for housing moves up along the upward sloping supply curve. That is, the quantity of housing supplied will increase, but housing prices will also increase as part of the same process.
YIMBYs aren’t arguing in favor of moving up a fixed supply curve – YIMBYs argue for policies that will shift the supply curve. The solution YIMBYs advocate isn’t simply to increase the quantity of housing supplied by building more housing, the solution YIMBYs advocate is to increase the housing supply through deregulation of the housing market. The YIMBY argument stresses that if the supply curve can’t shift right, then new houses will only be built in response to increases in demand driving prices higher and higher – which is what we are in fact seeing.
Pilkington says that increases in housing prices is positively correlated with increases in new homes being built as if he thinks he’s pointing to something that refutes the arguments of YIMBYs, without realizing that in fact what he’s pointing to is exactly what you would expect to see if the YIMBY argument is correct. This isn’t just performing an own goal, this is performing an own goal by doing a bicycle flip kick that scores the winning point for the other team at the championship match, then breaking out into a celebratory coordinated song and dance routine to Gangnam Style while pyrotechnics go off in the background.
As I’ve recently said in another context, this kind of mistake is something that would be easily avoided by anyone who had taken even a single Econ 101 course – and actually retained what they had learned. Sadly, some people can go very much further than Econ 101 and still not retain the basic concepts.
READER COMMENTS
David Seltzer
Mar 1 2024 at 4:32pm
Kevin, Thanks again. If one can grasp the difference between quantity demanded and change in demand, shift in the entire demand curve, they can understand quantity supplied and change in supply, shift in the entire supply curve. I review these concepts regularly. Lest we confuse them with the concept of elasticity.
Kevin Corcoran
Mar 1 2024 at 4:52pm
Three very distinct concepts! Changes in supply and demand – shifting a curve. Changes in quantity supplied and demanded – moving along a curve. And elasticity of supply and demand – the slope of the curve. If I had a nickel for every time I’ve seen one of these conflated with the other, I’d be able to swim in nickels Scrooge McDuck style.
David Seltzer
Mar 1 2024 at 5:34pm
Nickels? Why not silver dollars? Semper Fi!
Thomas L Hutcheson
Mar 1 2024 at 8:57pm
I agree with the analysis.
I would caution about stating the “objective” of increasing supply as “reducing cost or prices” of housing. [BTW, this applies to commercial spaces, not just housing and in fact most urban developments are both] This is because the relevant market may not coincide with the area that the allowed increased supply applies to.
If my city relaxed building restrictions in a given small area along a transit corridor near my house (as it appears it will, hooray!), the new housing build may well be quite expensive. If one does the numbers is a certain way, it could well be that the average cost per sq ft of space has risen. And there is nothing wrong with that! Of course somewhere in the metropolitan market prices will fall, but maybe unnoticeably because the effect is so diffuse. Proving that the increased supply reduced prices may be quite impossible.
Jim Glass
Mar 2 2024 at 1:01am
Ah, an economist who doesn’t even know what a correlation is. I wonder what lessons he draws from these? 🙂
Cody Boyer
Mar 2 2024 at 12:14pm
Reminds me of this Scott Sumner post: https://www.econlib.org/the-wittgenstein-test-2/.
(“What would the correlation of house prices and new construction look like if we increased the quantity of housing supplied without increasing supply?”)
Scott Sumner
Mar 2 2024 at 12:22pm
Excellent post. This is related to what I call “reasoning from a price change”. I see it all the time in macroeconomics. But in micro?
Hard to believe this guy is an economist—that’s a EC101 level mistake.
Pete Morris
Mar 2 2024 at 2:17pm
This same reasoning applies to the demand side of the story, too. An approach to housing policy informed by Econ 101 principles should be concerned with the price elasticity of both supply and demand. The more price-elastic is demand, the more an expansion of supply will increase the number of occupied housing units without making a big dent in housing prices.
It is tempting to think that housing demand is very inelastic, since housing is a basic need and population geography is sticky. But in the most expensive housing markets, it is reasonable to hypothesize that demand is more elastic. Not only is there a lot of global capital eager to move into markets such as New York and San Francisco, but there is a lot of latent demand of adults living with their parents and/or roommates. In such markets, expanding supply may spur new household formation rather than an actual decline in prices. Perhaps that is a socially desirable outcome, but perhaps so, too, are neighborhood and greenfield preservation. This is why my favorite lesson from Econ 101 is trade-offs. Always trade-offs.
Housing also is not a textbook generic commodity. The type of housing and neighborhood-specific location, location, location also matter. A lot. This is something that YIMBY arguments based primarily on lessons from Econ 101 often fail to address.
Kevin Erdmann
Mar 2 2024 at 8:28pm
The most expensive cities don’t really have a particularly unusual amount of immigration. They have very low rates of building. Prices are high specifically because housing demand is inelastic among the poorest households that are faced perennially with the threat of displacement. Hundreds of thousands of families have to move away each year because there is so little new housing.
Kevin Erdmann
Mar 2 2024 at 8:27pm
The most expensive cities don’t really have a particularly unusual amount of immigration. They have very low rates of building. Prices are high specifically because housing demand is inelastic among the poorest households that are faced perennially with the threat of displacement. Hundreds of thousands of families have to move away each year because there is so little new housing.
Comments are closed.