
My friend Ryan and his wife Abbie recently took a break from their two small kids and stayed in the Monterey area, going to a nice restaurant Friday evening and staying in a luxury hotel that night. He told me that they could have stayed in the Navy Lodge for about $100 but wanted to do it with style at the Clement Hotel on Cannery Row for $400. I told him that he and Abbie were demonstrating what we UCLA graduate students called the “oranges principle.” Here’s the explanation of that principle in Universal Economics.
Good and bad grapes: larger proportions of relatively good quality California oranges and grapes are shipped to New York than the proportions that remain in California. Are New Yorkers richer or more discriminating? Possibly—but the quality ratio is higher also in the poor districts of New York and the whole East Coast. The question can be posed for other goods: Why are disproportionately more expensive foreign cars and other “luxuries” exported than are purchased in the home country? Why do young parents go to expensive plays rather than movies on a higher percentage of their evenings out than do young childless couples? Why are “seconds” (slightly defective products) more heavily consumed at the site of manufacture? Why do more of the better, rather than the mediocre, students attend more distant colleges? Why should a tourist be more careful buying leather goods in Italy than when buying Italian exports in other countries? Why is most meat shipped to Alaska “deboned”?
The answers to these questions are based on an implication of the first law
Edition: current; Page: [128]
Table 9.1 Better Quality Is Shipped Away Prices of Grapes in New York = Transport Costs + Prices of Grapes in California Choice $1.50 = $.50 + $1.00 Standard $1.00 = .50 + .50 Relative Prices in New York Relative Prices in California 1.5 Standard for 1 Choice 2 Standard for 1 Choice of demand. In table 9.1, suppose California grapes a) cost 50¢ a pound to ship to New York, regardless of quality, and b) in California the choice grapes sell for $1 a pound and the standard grapes for 50¢ a pound. Since the cost is the same per unit of shipping either quality to New York, the price in New York is 50¢ higher than in California for both types. But in New York, a consumer of choice grapes sacrifices only 1.5 pounds of standard, whereas in California, one pound of choice costs two pounds of standard.
New Yorkers have a lower cost of choice grapes relative to standard grapes, and, therefore, in accordance with the first law of demand, they will demand a larger fraction of choice grapes than do Californians. In California, where standard grapes are cheaper than in New York relative to choice grapes, a larger fraction of standard grapes will be consumed. We don’t need to resort to conjectures about differences in “consumer tastes and preferences” to understand this phenomenon.
A general effect of an added cost to related products: an addition of a constant value to a high and to a low value will reduce the resulting ratio of the new values. The prices of high- and low-quality meat might be $10 and $5. Now, add $10 to each, which become $20 and $15. Though both absolute prices are increased equally, the high-quality meat becomes cheaper relative to the low-quality; or, in reverse, the low-quality becomes more expensive relative to the high-quality. Formerly, a purchase of high-quality meat was equivalent to giving up twice as much low-quality meat. But, with $10 added to both prices, the new price of the high-quality is lower relative to the low-quality—being only 1.33 rather than two times as expensive.
So the amount of high-quality meat demanded increases relative to the demanded amount of low-quality meat, when the price of each is increased by the same absolute amounts. The percentage reduction in demanded amount of low-quality meat is greater than for the higher-quality. Of the total demanded amount of meat, a larger proportion is now the higher-quality meat.
Edition: current; Page: [129]
Here’s how to apply it to Ryan and Abbie.
There’s a cost of having someone take care of kids: this could be a monetary cost or a “favor” cost: someone did them a favor and they owe that person a favor and even if they don’t ever repay the favor, they, as good people, take account of the cost their friends bear and feel some of it themselves. And because they love their kids, there’s also a cost because their kids will miss them and that counts in their computation of costs.
So let’s say the cost of having someone take care of the kids overnight is $200.
If they had no kids the relative price of Clement to Navy Lodge would be $400 to $100, or 4 to 1.
Since they have kids and there’s a cost the relative price of Clement to Navy Lodge is $600 to $300, or 2 to 1.
QED.
I was telling Ryan of another application of the principle. Back in the 1980s, my mentor and editor at Fortune, Dan Seligman, was writing a heavily researched article for Fortune on the gambling industry. Dan loved gambling. He noticed an empirical regularity and called me about it: people who had a higher cost of getting to Vegas (I think Dan went distance here, which is not a bad proxy for transportation cost) lost more per day than people who had a lower cost of getting to Vegas. Even though, as far as I know, he had never read Alchian and Allen, he correctly reasoned the same way they did.
His question to me was: is there a name for that principle? There absolutely is, I told him. It’s called the “oranges principle.” Needless to say, he wasn’t totally satisfied by my answer.
READER COMMENTS
Steve Fritzinger
Sep 1 2022 at 9:13am
Perhaps a more intuitive explanation would convince people of this effect.
In California, standard grapes are $1/lb and choice grapes are $2/lb. Californians see this and say, “These grapes are good but they’re not twice as good as those other grapes.”
Transport those same grapes to New York. Now the standard grapes are $2/lb and the choice grapes are $3/lb. New Yorkers see this and say, “Yes, these grapes are 50% better than those other grapes.”
Nicholas Janusch
Sep 1 2022 at 11:31am
I thought it was referred to as “the third law of demand.” Either way, not many economists know of this principle.
Bill
Sep 1 2022 at 1:11pm
My first exposure to this idea was Alchian and Allen, “Shipping the Good Apples Out.”
David Henderson
Sep 1 2022 at 2:00pm
Yes. That’s why I quoted Alchian and Allen at length in this post.
BC
Sep 2 2022 at 5:47pm
Is this oranges principle actually rational or a behavioral anomaly, some combination of mental accounting and sunk cost fallacy? If babysitting costs don’t depend on the choice of hotel, then why include them in comparing the relative cost of Navy Lodge to Clement? Why not include other child-rearing sunk costs, like healthcare, that are incurred even if the couple doesn’t go out, e.g., compare the relative costs of having children (instead of just babysitting) plus staying at Navy Lodge vs. having children plus staying at Clement? That would make the relative difference even smaller, but that also seems like a case of mental accounting, making different decisions based on which expenses are grouped together in the same “account”.
Shouldn’t they compare staying at Clement to staying at Navy Lodge plus enjoying $400-$100 = $300 of other goods? That’s true whether or not they add in the fixed cost of babysitting; the difference in opportunity cost is still $300 of other goods and services.
This comes up when people consider add-on options to cars and houses. Adding $5000 of fancy finishings to a new $500k house seems cheap: it only adds 1% to the price of the house. Yet, if they already own the house and are deciding whether to upgrade their finishings for $5k, then they compare $5k to 0 (the cost of keeping their existing finishings), and upgrading finishings seems expensive. But, $5k is $5k. Making a different decision based on whether one includes the value of the home seems like “mental accounting”.
BC
Sep 2 2022 at 6:05pm
The oranges principle applied to NY vs. CA grapes seems different, especially if CA grown grapes have to compete against NY grown grapes in NY. Suppose, NY grows grapes but not as efficiently as CA so that NY grapes cost 50% more to produce:
NY-grown Choice: 1.50
NY-grown Standard: 0.75
Since shipping cost from CA to NY is the same for Choice vs Standard, CA-grown Choice can compete against NY-grown Choice in NY, but CA-grown Standard is too expensive. Hence, we will see CA-grown Choice but not Standard in NY.
C. Carter
Sep 3 2022 at 5:16am
This principle seems incredibly useful for better understanding all kinds of situations. One that pops to mind is in considering sentence lengths for different crimes and repeat offenders.
Knut P. Heen
Sep 8 2022 at 7:36am
I love the principle. It is simple and give powerful predictions.
Add carbon-taxes and standard grapes will disappear from New York while choice grapes will disappear from California.
Comments are closed.