It may seem obvious that Taylor Swift “juiced the economy” during her two-year Eras world tour (Hannah Miao, “Billions in Cocktails and Friendship Bracelets: How Taylor Swift Juiced the Economy,” Wall Street Journal, December 8, 2024). But it is not. For example, the claim cannot be evaluated by simply counting how much money her fans paid in tickets, travel, outfits, etc., to attend her concerts.
Start with the question that Ms. Miao raises close to the end of her report but does not follow through:
There is debate among economists and analysts about how to measure Swift’s economic impact. Do her concerts just divert money that her fans would have spent elsewhere, or does she generate new activity?
Indeed, what her fans paid, they would have spent on something else—other shows or kinds of entertainment, vacations, household appliances or furniture, etc. (In the US, a ticket for an Eras concert reached more than $2,000 and sometimes much more.) The money could also have been saved, with means it would have served to finance investment somewhere in the economy. The objection that expenses related to Swift’s concerts produce “ripple effects” is voodoo economics: spending elsewhere would also produce “ripple effects,” if this expression has any meaning.
A more methodologically defendable estimate of Taylor Swift’s contribution to the economy would be their contribution to GDP. GDP is, by definition, the total production of the final goods at market prices, which is equal to total value added or, alternatively, the sum of all incomes. Only final goods to consumers are included in order to avoid double-counting—say, of the value of the wheat and the flour in the bread they serve to make. What’s important to understand is that the resources used to produce Swift’s concerts (the use of concert venues, the equipment, performers, sound engineers, other personnel, and so on, plus of course the singer’s time) would have otherwise been used to produce something else in the economy.
But to evaluate Taylor Swift’s (and her coproducers’) contribution to “the economy,” even a measure in terms of GDP is very imperfect. Her real contribution is the net benefits gained by the consumers. “Consumer surplus” is the technical term for this concept. It measures in dollars what the consumers gained from something they purchased over and above what they paid for it. The consumers who attended an Eras concert must have considered that it produced the highest consumer surplus that they could obtain with their money.
Besides the forbidding statistical problems of such measurements, there is a more basic problem: any dollar value of either GDP or consumer surplus is not sufficient to measure the “utility” of consumers. By utility, modern economic theory refers to a measure of how a consumer ranks different configurations of goods and situations in terms of his (or her, of course) own preferences. More money to purchase more goods and services will, ceteris paribus, increase one’s utility (and mutatis mutandis for less money), but money is not the only factor in satisfaction or happiness. Moreover, one dollar can give more utility to some individuals than to some other individuals.
One way to directly introduce utility in economic analysis is a model showing how individuals reach their “contract curves” by exchanging with each other. (Students of economics will see a general-equilibrium Edgeworth-Bowley box diagram pop up in their minds.) Most gains in utility come through exchange and trade: you work to, say, produce cars or write articles in order to buy a seat at a Taylor Swift concert; it’s like if you exchanged your piece of car or your articles with Ms. Swift and her organizers for their services.
Preferences and utility are subjective. They reside in the mind of each individual. As much as we can deduce that each party to an exchange gains utility from it (otherwise he would have declined the exchange), it is impossible, even conceptually, to aggregate utility across individuals to measure its net total increase or decrease. Economists speak of the impossibility of interpersonal utility comparisons. “The economy” is a set of individuals who interact to maximize their respective utility, not a bundle of physical objects. We cannot hope to calculate whether the resources employed for the Eras concerts would have produced more or less utility in some other allocation. We cannot hope to calculate a “net utility” figure that would tell us to which extent Taylor Swift brought a net contribution to the economy compared to the alternatives.
The impossibility of producing a precise number doesn’t matter because the same analytical tradition that leads to that conclusion also demonstrates a more general and useful proposition: an economic regime of free markets provides each individual (an individual randomly chosen, says Hayek) with the most opportunities to maximize each his utility through his acts of free exchange. Since some consumers do choose to attend Taylor Swift’s concerts instead of doing or buying something else, and bid up the price of tickets to make sure they get them (as opposed to those who chose to scalp their tickets), we can be sure that, to the extent the economy is free, the result is economically efficient.
READER COMMENTS
Thomas Leonard Knapp
Dec 16 2024 at 12:29pm
“what her fans paid, they would have spent on something else—other shows or kinds of entertainment, vacations, household appliances or furniture, etc. ”
There’s at least one plausible exception to that substitution factor:
Say I’m a Taylor Swift fan, and really want to see her in concert, and calculate that it will cost me, say, $2,500 to purchase tickets, travel, lodging, etc., to do that.
What if instead of taking that money out of my savings account, or foregoing other expenditures I would normally otherwise make, I take on a second temporary job, or start volunteering for overtime shifts at my job, to finance the concert attendance? In that case, I am increasing my productivity and “growing the economy” by working hours I would not otherwise have worked.
Craig
Dec 16 2024 at 12:41pm
“Indeed, what her fans paid, they would have spent on something else”
Indeed even what her non-fans were forced to pay to subsidize the construction of some of the stadiums she played in would have been spent on something else, like, I dunno, stupid things like my kids’ 529 plan. 😉
Pierre Lemieux
Dec 16 2024 at 2:23pm
Craig: You are right. Any measurement, or attempt at measurement, of Taylor Smith “juicing the economy” would have to deduct the opportunity cost of the public funds spent on indirectly subsidizing her. That’s included in my qualification “to the extent the economy is free.” Nothing is perfect, but it could certainly be less imperfect than it is now.
steve
Dec 16 2024 at 1:49pm
You seem to be saying that spending on Taylor Swift cant result in real economic growth. Obviously, we do get real growth. Why couldn’t her concerts cause that?
Steve
Pierre Lemieux
Dec 16 2024 at 2:05pm
Steve: Spending does not cause any real economic growth in the sense of increased prosperity and utility. (If it did, “modern monetary theory” would bring all to nirvana.) What causes economic growth is investment and entrepreneurship for the purpose of producing goods and services demanded by consumers to increase their utility.
robc
Dec 16 2024 at 2:21pm
I think he is saying the exact opposite. She is increasing the economy by the difference in consumer surplus for her concerts vs the consumer surplus of the second best opportunity for that money.
Its just not as much as the raw numbers suggest. And it is basically incalculable, as we would need the utility difference for each individual.
Pierre Lemieux
Dec 16 2024 at 2:13pm
Thomas: That’s a good but, I think, invalid point.
First, it is unlikely that, with his infinite (or near-infinite) desires, the consumer you mention did not already equalize his work time and leisure time at the margin. It is because of individuals’ infinite desires for goods and services that, as the cost of leisure increased, it has been overcome by the income effect at some point: people do not take much more leisure time than, say, 50 years ago. We could think of rare cases, such as a desert hermit who, on his annual trip to the village hardware store, sees Taylor Swift on a TV screen and immediately drops his contemplation lifestyle and goes get a job at McDonald’s to be able to buy a concert ticket. But even this case is taken care of by my second argument.
My second point concerns most individuals. On a free labor market, most individuals are paid the value of their marginal product. (I exclude cases like Beethoven, Bach, or Shakespeare.) If we can say that an individual “grows the economy,” it is his economy that he grows. Except perhaps infinitesimally, he does not increase GDP for anybody else nor anybody else’s consumer surplus.
It is true that an individual’s trade of his labor services for a wage, and of his wage for (say) Taylor Swift’s services, will benefit the people with whom he exchanges. While helping himself, he helps these people get on their contract curve. Yet, his contribution to other’s utility is typically very small, and cannot be measured anyway. What we do know is that it is because all individuals get on their contract curve (trade with each other) that all of them can get (relatively) rich–which was my core argument on “juicing the economy.”