Economists are often suspicious of gifts in kind, arguing that the same money value in cash provides more “utility” to the recipient (puts her in a more preferred situation) because she can use the cash to buy what is on top of her preference scale (her “utility function” in economics). If you don’t buy the gift that she would have bought for herself, your gift is worth less to her than what you paid for. (See Joel Waldfogel, “The Deadweight Loss of Christmas,” American Economic Review 83[5] [1993].)
There are many objections or qualifications to this idea. In certain circumstances, a gift in kind will provide more utility to the recipient. If you know your recipient enough to have a good intuition of her preference scale, you may be able to approximate what she would have herself purchased with the cash. A well-chosen gift in kind signals that you know what she likes or that you have made some effort to please her. The pleasure and surprise in opening many boxes also count. This at least partly explains the resilient popularity of gifts in kind.
In their microeconomics textbook Price Theory and Applications: Decisions, Markets, and Information (seventh edition, Cambridge University Press, 2005, p. 110), Jack Hirshleifer, Amihai Glazer, and David Hirshleifer express a similar idea:
Does that mean that donors should always give cash? Not necessarily! A noncash gift may signal that the donor cares enough to devote time and thought to what the recipient desires or needs. Even if the choice itself misses the mark, the recipient may value the expression of concern that lies behind it.
For somebody whom the giver does not know well, cash or a gift card can be the best option. Yet, another option has developed which, even for persons you know well, marries the advantages of cash and of gifts in kind: wish lists, especially online like that of Amazon. You are sure to give her something she wants and there are boxes to open.
Still another reason for some gifts in kind is that the recipient may ignore how much utility something will give her. Your gift may make her discover it. Although economists assume that preferences do not change, it is mainly for methodological reasons. We sometimes discover things that we previously did not think we would enjoy.
Not only the preferences of a gift recipient must be considered, but also her budget. Any choice of buying or not buying is the product of two factors: preferences and budget constraint. A gift has an income effect. The recipient will be able to consume more than before she got the gift. This income effect may be canceled if your recipient gives you the same value in gifts that you give her. Indeed, this is what happens on Christmas, although the wealthier of the two gift-exchangers will frequently end up transferring a net amount of money (that is, of goods) to the poorer one.
But even when the income effect of receiving gifts is canceled by the cost of giving gifts in return, playing this exchange game gives utility to the two participants. Otherwise, one of them would not participate. In human relations, exchange is omnipresent—and much preferable to violence. As Adam Smith suggested, man is an animal who trades.
I have ignored the special case of business gifts, which are part of a more standard exchange. A gift to one’s customer is a price paid in the hope of continuous patronage. But note that an exchange of gifts between two friends, lovers, or family members can also be considered as a price paid for the continuation of a mutually beneficial exchange relationship. The festive atmosphere of Christmas adds to the utility produced by the exchange.
All this illustrates that economics is not about money, except in the subfield of monetary theory. It is not about telling one how to behave efficiently, even if it can inform one against many fallacies (the sunk cost fallacy, for example); it is about understanding individual choices and their actual social consequences.
READER COMMENTS
Matthias
Nov 26 2021 at 7:41pm
A big part of social gift giving is about signalling to third parties, too.
Pierre Lemieux
Nov 27 2021 at 11:18am
Good point, Matthias! I am not sure what you mean by “SOCIAL gift giving,” though. The person who gives money to his church or to his alma mater and has a plaque in his honor or a school named after him? Or who creates a large philanthropic foundation? Anthropologists also used to make much of reciprocal, large-scale gift-giving in primitive societies. If “social” means between two persons or more in the same society, signaling must also be one motivation of large gifts; at the top of the scale, “It’s a Christmas gift from my husband,” said she to her neighbor, pointing to the new Porche in the driveway.
Knut P. Heen
Nov 29 2021 at 11:05am
I have sometimes received gifts I did not know existed. I could therefore not have bought them myself. I hate shopping.
Craig
Nov 29 2021 at 11:50am
“I hate shopping.”
Me too, part of the reason my pre-marital savings rate was absolutely stupendous. Then I got married and now my wife, aka chief of family procurement, regularly degausses my credit cards.
Henri Hein
Nov 29 2021 at 2:11pm
The best gifts are the ones the recipient needed, but did not know they needed it.
The worst gifts are the ones the giver wanted the recipient to have, regardless of her wants or needs. I think this is a big source of waste in the gift giving ritual. “I’m a sports fan, so I’m going to give away sports tickets and swag.” For those of us who don’t like sports, we end up with duds.
Pierre Lemieux
Nov 29 2021 at 3:22pm
Henri: However, a gift that the recipient doesn’t like but that the giver loves has the potential of bringing much utility to the latter if they are living together or keep in close contact. You give to your wife something that you love but that she doesn’t like and in no time you can borrow it permanently. Whether one wants to live with such a person (“you”) is her choice; some benefits may compensate for the costs.
Andrea Mays
Dec 7 2021 at 1:18am
This variation of a gift swap gets closer to optimal distribution of gifts within a group:
Everyone contributes one wrapped gift of a predetermined maximum value. Participants in the swap each choose a number from a hat determining the order in which the participants will choose from among the gifts under the tree. The first participant chooses a gift, unwraps it and reveals it to the group. The second person either takes the gift the first person unwrapped OR chooses another gift from umder the tree. Successive participants can choose from among all of the revealed gifts OR can choose from among the (wrapped) gifts. If someone chooses a gift previously unwrapped, the person from whom the gift was taken chooses another gift from under the tree. The process continues until the last participant has taken a gift from someone or chosen the last gift from under the tree.
This process seems to match gifts to preferences pretty well, resulting in increased satisfaction over random gift assignment.
This process plays out every year at a friend’s holiday party of (mostly) aerospace engineers. Preferences are heterogenous!
PS Least popular gift? Chocolate covered crickets.
Comments are closed.