Trade with China undoubtedly costs jobs in specific industries. However there is no evidence that it has any impact on the overall number of jobs in the US. Last year I did a number posts criticizing a study by Autor, Dorn and Hanson, for drawing aggregate conclusions from cross-sectional data. Later Paul Krugman made the same criticism:
OK, what about the effect on overall employment? In general, you can’t answer that with a similar computation, because it all depends on offsetting policies. If monetary and fiscal policy are used to achieve a target level of employment – as they generally were prior to the 2008 crisis – then a first cut at the impact on overall employment is zero. That is, trade deficits meant 2 million fewer manufacturing jobs and 2 million more in the service sector.
. . .Up through 2007 we basically had a Fed which raised rates whenever it thought the economy was overheating; in the absence of the China shock it would have raised rates sooner and faster, so you just can’t use the results of the cross-section regression – which doesn’t reflect monetary policy, which was the same for everyone – to predict how things would have turned out.
Since then a number of papers have provided support for the Sumner/Krugman critique. First there was one by Jonathan Rothwell, and more recently by Ildikó Magyari. Notice how Magyari distinguishes between microeconomic and macroeconomic effects:
What is the impact of Chinese imports on employment of US manufacturing firms? Previous papers have found a negative effect of Chinese imports on employment in US manufacturing establishments, industries, and regions. However, I show theoretically and empirically that the impact of offshoring on firms, which can be thought of as collections of establishments – differs from the impact on individual establishments – because offshoring reduces costs at the firm level. These cost reductions can result in firms expanding their total manufacturing employment in industries in which the US has a comparative advantage relative to China, even as specific establishments within the firm shrink. Using novel data on firms from the US Census Bureau, I show that the data support this view: US firms expanded manufacturing employment as reorganization toward less exposed industries in response to increased Chinese imports in US output and input markets allowed them to reduce the cost of production. More exposed firms expanded employment by 2 percent more per year as they hired more (i) production workers in manufacturing, whom they paid higher wages, and (ii) in services complementary to high-skilled and high-tech manufacturing, such as R&D, design, engineering, and headquarters services. In other words, although Chinese imports may have reduced employment within some establishments, these losses were more than offset by gains in employment within the same firms. Contrary to conventional wisdom, firms exposed to greater Chinese imports created more manufacturing and nonmanufacturing jobs than non-exposed firms.
But the media loves a good story, and the “China stealing American jobs” meme just won’t go away. Here’s a recent article from The Economist:
Since relatively few industrial robots are in use in the American economy, the total job loss from robotisation has been modest: between 360,000 and 670,000. By comparison, analysis published in 2016 found that trade with China between 1999 and 2011 may have left America with 2m fewer jobs than it would otherwise have had. Yet, if the China trade shock has largely run its course, the robot era is dawning.
That’s very misleading. It’s possible that there are 2 million specific workers who lost jobs because of Chinese trade. But there is no evidence that the net number of US jobs was reduced at all.
Fortunately, the public doesn’t seem to be buying all this gloom and doom, as support for trade is soaring dramatically higher. And Trump seems to have abandoned his proposal for 45% tariffs on Chinese goods.
PS. I am on vacation, and my comments will be few and far between.
READER COMMENTS
E. Harding
Apr 16 2017 at 11:32am
I think it’s plausible enough that trade with China has resulted in fewer American jobs than in the counterfactual. However, I’ve seen no evidence to suggest any long-term effect of U.S. trade with China on the U.S. unemployment rate.
Philo
Apr 16 2017 at 12:25pm
Tyler Cowen never goes on vacation!
[Typo fixed–Econlib Ed.]
Thaomas
Apr 16 2017 at 1:05pm
The measure “number of jobs” lost or not lost is intuitively appealing, the better measure is what is the GE effect on wages of different classes. Of course the GE has to specify whether the Fed is assumed to be following an optimal monetary policy.
Paul Bogle
Apr 16 2017 at 4:08pm
Scott, you need a vacation. Enjoy!
(I look forward to you returning fresh)
Jon Murphy
Apr 16 2017 at 4:50pm
Great read, but I seem to get an error when I click on the Magyari link.
Scott Sumner
Apr 16 2017 at 9:50pm
Jon, Sorry about that, I won’t be able to fix it from here.
Cyril Morong
Apr 16 2017 at 9:55pm
If there were 2 million fewer jobs in 2011, what would the unemployment rate supposedly have been that year without trade from China? Much lower?
Look at 2007. The unemployment rate was 4.6%. What if the number of jobs that had been lost by that time was 1.333 million (about 2/3 of 2 million-2007 is about 2/3 of the way to 2011 from 1999).
If I had that number of jobs to BLS stats, I get an unemployment rate of 3.75%. That would be pretty low. I think most economists would say that was well below the natural rate.
So if the job loss numbers are correct, does that mean no trade with China would have given us a 3.75% unemployment rate?
Thaomas
Apr 17 2017 at 7:31am
@ Cyril Morong
You are right. That is a good way of illustrating the point that “number of jobs” is not the right metric for measuring the impact of trade with China (or trade generally or technological change). One needs a complete model that gets down to changes in equilibrium wages of different kinds of labor and transitions from one kind to another.
pyroseed13
Apr 17 2017 at 9:19am
Why exactly should we care what the effect of trade is on total employment? Even with offsetting, Magyari concedes that the new jobs created are not necessarily going to the same people, so some people will still end up quite worse off than otherwise. But putting all of this aside, the purpose of trade is not to increase, decrease, or offset unemployment, but to improve economic efficiency. It’s certainly possible than without trade with China total employment would be higher overall, but whether we should care about that is an open question.
Per Kurowski
Apr 17 2017 at 9:38am
How many jobs might have been lost, not to Chinese workers but to Chinese robots? What if US, as a consequence of not giving its own robots a fair chance to develop, would end up with 2nd or 3rd class robots?
Brandon Berg
Apr 17 2017 at 12:46pm
Isn’t the ADH thesis that this is a local phenomenon, where the labor market isn’t adjusting because workers are hanging out in areas with weak local labor markets, rather than moving to where the jobs are? Is that an issue that can be addressed by national monetary policy, or would the monetary policy needed to increase employment in some areas enough to make up for those areas with depressed employment lead to runaway inflation?
Jon Murphy
Apr 17 2017 at 4:04pm
@Scott-
It’s not an issue with your link. I found it’s an issue with the Columbia website. I emailed their webmaster.
Scott Sumner
Apr 19 2017 at 12:10pm
Brandon, I believe they also claim it’s a national problem.
Kristian Morey
Apr 21 2017 at 3:18pm
Scott you mention: “Since then a number of papers have provided support for the Sumner/Krugman critique.” Do you have a list of the other papers?
Comments are closed.