Adam Smith’s central example of technological change and improvement in consumer-durables was the watch. When writing the Wealth of Nations, he hypothesized that the price of watches fell nearly 95% over the past century.
This diminution of price has, in the course of the present and preceding century, been most remarkable in those manufactures of which the materials are the coarser metals. A better movement of a watch, than about the middle of the last century could have been bought for twenty pounds, may now perhaps be had for twenty shillings. WN I.11.243
A new paper in the Quarterly Journal of Economics asks – was Smith right? To answer the question, authors Kelly and O Grada use the reported value of over 3,200 stolen watches from criminal trials in the Old Bailey in London from 1685 to 1810.
Before allowing for quality improvements, they find that the real price of watches in nearly all categories falls steadily by 1.3% a year, equivalent to a fall of 75% over a century. If you allow modest improvement in the quality of silver watches, the authors find an annual fall in real prices of 2%, or 87% over a century. Very close to Smith’s observation.
Watches consisted of two parts, the mechanism and the case. Most of the cost of a silver watch mechanism was the labour involved in technical construction of the mechanism – the cutting, filing, and assembling of all the parts. By assuming constant mark-up, the authors’ are able to assess the rise of labour productivity in watchmaking by comparing how the price of a watch fell relative to nominal wages. During the period 1680-1810, real wages were roughly constant, so this rise in labour productivity is similar to the fall in real prices of watches.
At the time, London did not have a state-run police force, so criminal prosecutions for theft were privately initiated. Watches were valuable – costing more than a week’s wages for the average labourer – and they were easily resold, making them a hot commodity. Interestingly enough however, the authors show that over the period, watch ownership among working men rose steadily through the eighteenth century and had become extensive by 1800.
The broader implication of the paper concerns the very nature of the Industrial Revolution. First, the authors use the evidence presented in this study to support the claim of a much earlier beginning to the Industrial Revolution (late 1600s) than the more commonly accepted date of the mid 1800s. Second, the authors want to use this as support for a particular mechanism by which the Industrial Revolution occurred. The crucial connection for innovation, as they see it, is the relationship between elite inventors and skilled artisans. Once the technical breakthrough of watchmaking occurred, “England’s extensive tradition of metal working and the relative absence of restrictions on hiring apprentices, along with an extensive market of affluent consumers, allowed its watch industry to expand rapidly.”
But the paper itself seems to point to a very important explanatory element. The institutions protecting property rights – the system of private prosecutions that prevailed in England prior to the introduction of the police – were relatively low cost and easy to access for all segments of society. This is demonstrated in the paper by the fact that watch-thievery was widely prosecuted (the cost of using the courts was presumably less than the value of the watch) and that everyone from affluent gentlemen, labourers, servants, and drunks could reasonably expect justice. Mark Koyama’s work looks at how private clubs operated at the time, showing how these private order institutions were often successful in ameliorating the problem of crime.
READER COMMENTS
Mike Linksvayer
Oct 30 2016 at 4:59pm
cf today’s non-competes, occupational licensing most recently mentioned on this site in http://www.econlib.org/archives/2016/10/the_ceas_mixed_1.html
Jose Romeu Robazzi
Oct 31 2016 at 7:47am
Great post. It shows very clearly that productivity enhancements, thos of the kind that produces cheaper consumer products, therefore benefiting the entire society, are not the result of “knowledge” only.
It is common these days to praise scientific development, as a the single most important factor in mankind’s evolution, but, as the research described in the post shows, entrepreneurs (investors and technicians) and institutions (property rights protection and low barriers to entry on skilled workers) play a vital role as well.
As prof. Sumner recently said in a post over at TheMoneyIllusion, economists these days should study more economic history.
Thanks for sharing this, Prof. Skarbek.
Jeff
Nov 1 2016 at 10:27am
I tried to post something like this a few days ago but it never appeared.
I don’t understand this. How can you have rising labor productivity for over a century but no rise in real wages?
[Hi, Jeff. We do not have any unposted comments by you in the last few days. Feel free to email me at webmaster@econlib.org if you think something did get lost.–Econlib Ed.]
Comments are closed.