Competition is a buzzword. Everyone loves it, but there are vastly different interpretations of this precious concept. These different interpretations lead to strongly conflicting policy recommendations.
Imagine you and your super wealthy friend bet on who will win the 100 metres at the Olympics. Your friend wins the bet. But then you find out that the race was rigged. Your friend had bought off seven of the eight contestants. “That’s unfair! Then it wasn’t a real contest” you cry out. Now, imagine your friend shrugging his shoulders and responding, “It was a competition. See, there were so many runners.”
That response would strike us all as ridiculous. The sheer number of racers is not relevant. What would have been necessary for it to be true competition and a true race is for all the runners to give their best to win. But that wasn’t the case. And thus, it wasn’t competition; it wasn’t a race.
This story demonstrates a precious insight into economic theory. To see that, consider one of the dominant models in economics, that of perfect competition. Roughly, this suggests that for a market to be perfectly competitive, goods must be homogenous, there must be an infinite number of sellers, no transaction costs, and perfect information. Let’s focus solely on the infinite number of sellers. In reality, there’ll never be an infinite number, but imagine that we have an industry with many sellers such that we would be content that this condition for perfect competition holds for our practical considerations.
Remember the race example I mentioned earlier. There were eight runners. Would this number be “enough” to have competition? Initially, one would think yes, in general this is so. When we have many runners (as these are the companies in the market), we should expect there to be competition.
But not so fast. Recall that in our example, seven of the eight runners had been bought off. They had not given their best; they lost on purpose. There had been no competition – it was all a sham. Unrealistic as this example may be, it demonstrates an important lesson: we want a certain kind of behaviour when we want competition. We want racers to give their best to win the gold medal, we want athletes to train as hard as possible, and we want entrepreneurs, managers, and workers to work relentlessly to improve their products, make them cheaper, and align them better to what the consumers want. What we want is not this or that number of runners or sellers. What we want is a certain attitude.
Two lessons follow from this. Firstly, a monopolist, in the sense of a company that is the sole seller in some market, can mean absolute competition. For it is enough that the company has the right mindset, i.e., acts competitively by relentlessly striving to improve their product etc. So, what is needed is this competitive mindset. And for its emergence it is necessary that potential competitors have “freedom of entry”. The threat of competitors potentially entering the market keeps the incumbent company on its toes. Then, we may have only one seller – but this seller is competing.
Secondly, a market that has many companies does not necessarily have to be competitive. Imagine we had an economic system akin to the guild systems of past centuries. In such a scenario, there could be hundreds of smiths in the country, but all of them with their specified area that they, and only they, supply. There may well be no competitive mindset here, as the smiths need not worry about customers choosing a rival – as rivals are not allowed to enter the market.
Capitalism as an economic system is intended to lead entrepreneurs to produce what consumers want. To ensure that consumer wants are satisfied, competition is imperative. But this is about a mindset, an attitude. It is irrelevant whether there is one spectacular entrepreneur in a market that outcompetes others such that his company is the only seller. Instead, it is about how entrepreneurs act: are they vigilant, striving, restless, endlessly looking for improvements? If yes, then we consumers have the competition we want. If not, then we consumers must protest. And then we consumers must recall that for sellers to have this competitive mindset, we need “the complete absence of institutional restrictions upon entry”. This freedom for entry (and for exit) is what makes for competitive markets. Not an arbitrarily defined number of sellers.
Max Molden is a PhD student at the University of Hamburg. He has worked with European Students for Liberty and Prometheus – Das Freiheitsinstitut. He regularly publishes at Der Freydenker.
READER COMMENTS
Johannes Steffens
May 30 2023 at 12:10pm
Thanks for the interesting article!
At one point you write that competition is a mindset or attitude. But then you also say “it is about how entrepreneurs act”. Is this essentially the same? Or couldn’t one argue that the two things differ?
Best
JS
David Seltzer
May 31 2023 at 4:13pm
Johannes, if I may, how entrepreneurs act is the result of subjective value as it comes from the human mind. The individual is the valuer. Apologies to Max as I do not mean to speak for him.
Max Molden
Jun 2 2023 at 1:49am
David, thanks for pointing to that connection. I think that Johannes is correct to point out that it is not clearly specified in my text!
I’d add that not only are subjective values crucial, but also our beliefs. So when we act we want something and we believe something. The belief is also subjective. In this sense, our mindset/attitude is not the same as our action, but our mindset is decisive for our action.
David Seltzer
May 31 2023 at 3:55pm
Max: “The sheer number of racers is not relevant.” Reuben Kessel’s study of competition among bond underwriters: With one underwriter bidding for the business, the spread between the underwriting and market offering to investors was was $15.74. With two underwriters bidding, it fell to $12.64. With three, it fell a little more, to $12.36. Competition between only two underwriters was enough to affect market pricing.
Max Molden
Jun 2 2023 at 1:50am
Thanks for that remark, David. Could you send me a link to that paper? Sounds interesting!
David Seltzer
Jun 2 2023 at 2:39pm
Max, per your request.
A Study of the Effects of Competition in the Tax-exempt Bond Market
Reuben Kessel
Journal of Political Economy
Vol. 79, No. 4 (Jul. – Aug., 1971), pp. 706-738 (33 pages)
Published By: The University of Chicago Press
Max Molden
Jun 4 2023 at 9:02am
Much appreciated, thank you!
Maniel
Jun 3 2023 at 10:31pm
Max, interesting post. In the USA, the “economic experts” in our government have a tendency to block mergers and acquisitions. Those same experts seem to know whether or not I hold any stock (shares) in the the target companies. I, of course, am strictly impartial, but it does seem to me that not only am I unable to sell my shares at the price the acquirer is offering, in their haste to preserve “perfect competition,” those experts are preventing potentially valuable synergies. I would be interested in any comments.
Thank you.
Max Molden
Jun 4 2023 at 9:18am
Thanks for your comment, Maniel! You write that “in their haste to preserve “perfect competition,” those experts are preventing potentially valuable synergies.” And I deeply agree with this. The best way to satisfy consumer wants may well be the merging of two companies (and even having a monopolist, i.e, only one company in the market). And those who know best will be the entrepreneurs, not some government officials.
Two more points: Firstly, the consumers can, if they are willing to bear the costs, punish companies they find too big. But often it happens that we consumers prefer the lower prices at Amazon to buying local.
Secondly, insights of public choice theory are crucial in assessing antitrust measures. These intervention are vulnerable to being captured/distorted by special interest.
If you are interested in a detailed examination of antitrust, I recommend studying Armentano, e.g., his https://mises.org/library/antitrust-case-repeal.
Maniel
Jun 4 2023 at 7:52pm
Thank you for your thoughtful response, Max. Much appreciated, not least because we are in agreement.
Comments are closed.